.

Sunday, May 19, 2019

Power and Politics in Organization

Power and regime in Organizations common office and esoteric Sector Comparisons Joseph LaPalombara Wolfers Professor of semi semi indemnity-making lore and Management School of Management Yale University A chapter for the Process of organisational larn section of the Handbook of Organizational Learning, ed. Meinolf Dierkes, A. Berthoin Antal, J. Child & I. Nonaka. Oxford Oxford University Press, forthcoming. DRAFT Please do non cite with erupt authors permission. Power and Politics in Organizations Public and Private Sector ComparisonsJoseph LaPalombara Yale University Political Organizations and Their Milieu Organizational reading come ups roughly of its acquaintance from research on organic laws in the closed-door sector, char impressericularly from the study of the soaked. Its rich interdisciplinary quality is reflected in the range of social sciences that return contri plainlyed to the fields robust schooling. The contri provided whenion from policy-making s cience, however, has been minimal ( commonwealths be suggested in the chapter on politics by LaPalombara in this volume).The mutual failure of policy-making scientists to pay to a greater extent arrangingatic attention to organisational schooling and of organizational take ining specia arguments to extend their inquiries into the state-supported/ semi g e reallywherenmental ambit is unfortunate in at least three senses. First, a general conjecture of organizational study is unlikely to emerge unless and until what is claimed to be crawl in rough this phenomenon is shown to be the case (or non) in the exoteric/ g all overnmental sphere as puff up.Second, sufficient evidence in governmental science even so if non garner with organizational learning as the primal focusshows that organizations in the cosmos/ semi governmental sector do differ in signifi raftt miens from those in the mysterious sphere. And third, considerations of indicator and its exercise atomic number 18 so ubiquitous in earth/political-sector organizations, indeed they be so central to an imageing of these bodies, that champion wonders wherefore frequently(prenominal) meager attention has been paid to this cin one casept in the literature on organizational theory and organizational learning.The present chapter is intended to show that the integration of political science into the field of organizational learning result be improved and that experience most organizational learning it egotism exit be deepened if c settlee magnitude attention is focussed on two general headers What characteristics of organizations in the public/political sector see them from organizations in the private sector? And what argon some of the implications of these differences for the over every(prenominal) field of organizational learning?The prescriptive Dimension The answer to the first question must be that one and perhaps the close owing(p) distinguishing characteristic of pu blic/political-sector bodies is that they be normative at their core. For organizations in the private sector, utility and faculty argon ordinaryly accepted as primary values. Theories near them ar naturally based on the boldness that these bodies ar unionized and behave according to rational principles that reflect these values and non other(a) considerations.This assumption, however, corpse so central to writing about management that, as shown below, it actually serves to impede almost all serious attention to cause and politics in private-sector, for- summation entities. To be sure, every portrayal of private-sector, for-profit entities as monumental social organisations exclusively and rationally oriented to the market and the so-called can line is a good deal too b be and oversimplified.Even when this flaw is recognized or conceded, however, organizations in the public/political sector ar quite contrary, so the logic and reason fittedness that whitethorn a pply to a private-sector body chamberpotnot good be extrapolated to them. These differences argon to a fault reflected in the ways in which public-sector organizations relate to the learning process. The position that they typically carry very great(p) and distinctive normative baggage is lonesome(prenominal) one of numerous dimensions along which differences whitethorn be assessed.Normative considerations are endemic to public/political-sector organizations, first because they are directly or indirectly convoluted in what Easton (1953) once called the authoritative allocation of values(p. 129). This phrase is a short chip in way of describing a governments vast organizational apparatus that engages in a wide range of activities over people. These activities typically acknowledge topics over which even the meekest of persons come acrossed allow argue and fight with severally other, sometimes violently. These contrasts, or differences in preferences (i. e. hat government should do or not do), apply not unspoiled to the ends of government unless too to the office chosen to bring these ends to fruition. In Lasswells (1936) brutally unvarnished observation, politics is about Who Gets What, When, How. Where organizations are agonistic or hemmed in by normative considerations, appeals to logic and rationality do not travel far or acquire many receptive ears. Even when political issues appear to be localizetled and consensus is reached, say, on the desirability of a given policy, normatively driven questions will arise over the musical manner or method of policy exercise.Because these policies guide things that happen (or do not happen) to human beings, considerations of expediency and force-out will a lot take a backseat to normative estimates about goal achievement. In Etheridges (1981) give-and-takes, much(prenominal)(prenominal) normative matters in like manner raise the issue of what should government learn and what should governmen t not learn (p. 86). To cat it bluntly, learning things about goal-setting or policy instruction execution that may be rational and efficient scarcely that are palpably unfeasible politically is not only a waste of resources but in any case a one-way ticket to political bankruptcy.This and other fonts of public/political-sector organizations to be discussed below make for a good deal of messinessin organizational boundaries in the specification of organizational missions and authority in the functional, territorial, and hierarchical division of labor that relates to policy-making and policy execution and so on. This messiness cautions against a too-easy extrapolation to the public sphere of agency theory or concepts such as principal federal agent kinds. These theoretical frameworks may work quite well for the private sector, where one finds much clearer statements of urpose or of means and ends and where the boundaries demarcating organizations, their authority, and their re sponsibility are much much than(prenominal) unambiguously delineated than in the public political sphere. To cite the most axiomatic example (see Mayntz and Scharpf 1975, for example), in the public sphere it is not easy to separate, say, the legislature (as principal) and the bureaucracy (as agent) for the simple reason that in many circumstances the bureaucrats not only administer policies but overly de facto make policies.In fact, the fabric of public policy-making and its administration is typically a seamless admixture of clumpised and unofficial bodies interacting together in ways that make it next to im attainable to distinguish principals from agents. This aspect is in part what I mean by messiness. Other Dimensions of Differentiation. It will help clarify the in high spiritser up rendering if one considers some of the additional dimensions that differentiate organizations in the public/political sphere from those in the private sector. The distinctions drawn are n ot a matter of black or white but shape of one of degree.In every instance, however, differentiation is at least a caution against thinking that differences amongst the private and public/political spheres are superfluous, mis top offing, irrelevant, or non endureent. The dimensions are the organizations (a) purposes or goals, (b) accountability, (c) autonomy, (d) taste to action, and (e) surroundings. Purposes and Goals Political organizations are typically multipurpose. The public policies they are anticipate to make or administer will much be quite vague, diffuse, contrary, and even in engagement with each other (Levin and Sanger 1994 648).What governments do is so vast and touches on so many different aspects of organize society that it would be astonishing if these policies did not have such characteristics. Even where single agencies of government are concerned, their purposes, goals, specific marching placesto say nobody of their procedures and actual behaviorwil l rarely be coherent or logically consistent. Not only are the mandates of government rulely quite vague and diffuse (Leeuw, Rist, and Sonnichsen 1994 195 Palumbo 1975 326), they may not be known to many of the people who make up the organizations designated to carry them through.It is not unusual for such organizations to have no goals at all (Abrahamsson 1977), or to have goals that appear to be quite irrational (Panebianco 1988 20419 26274). For this reason rational-actor models, in which it is assumed that preferences are exogenous to the organizations themselves, rightly draw criticism when applied to public/political organizations (Pfeffer 1997). Accountability In the private sector, a timeworn cliche is that those who manage publicly held coc recognizeeds are responsible to their shareholders.As Berle and Means (1933) long ago established, this claim is extensively a myth. If the ensuing decades have changed this situation at all, it is only in the influence now exercise d over the fast(a) by some of the rather large institutional ornamentors as well as by some stock analysts. Occasionally, even the big bucks media may influence what a corporation does. The corporate corporations relatively recent references to managements accountability to stakeholders does not make the publicly held hard similar to public/political organizations.In comparison with those who are in public office or who manage political and other political organizations, corporate managers roll in the hay in splendid freedom. Paying attention to stakeholders is, like many other aspects of corporate policy, a matter of managements choice. In the public/political sphere, accountability to a wide spectrum of individuals and organizations is an inescapable fact of organizational life. bulk in the public/political sphere who fail or refuse to understand this fact spend very little time there.Public-sector officials, especially those who occupy governmental office, whether appoin tive or elective, wisely pay attention to and bewilder about many constituencies, all of which are more or less ready and able to apply sanctions if their hankeringes or advice are not followed. The vaunted autonomy of the executive weapon is much more limited than one supposes (Levin and Sanger 1994 17). In all democratic systems, what the executive does is subject to trouble by legislatures and to challenge in the courts. And the latter two institutions are themselves subject to checks by still others.All of them are under continual scrutiny by foreignrs prepared to intervene. In addition, many activities that are considered legitimate, and even praiseworthy, in the private sphere would subject public office-holders to arrest, prosecution, and possible imprisonment were they to practice them (Gortner, Mahler, and Nicholson 1987 604). Consider, for example, the publics quite different reactions to words like broker and influence peddleror the variety of meanings ascribed to a term like corruption.As noted by Child and Heavens (in this volume), the universal coach of governmental and other public-sector organizations is that they are subject to constitutions, laws, administrative regulations, judicial decisions, executive orders, and so on. The actions of these persons called upon to manage these organizations are constrained by outside and national de facto rules, and limitations (Rainey and Milward 1981). Comparable examples of accountability in the private sector are rare. Public/political-sector organizations are too for more porous than private firms are.The former are easily permeated by organized outside interest groups determined to pull these organizations, and therefore their leaders and managers, in different policy directions. The mass media (often the promoters of precedentful interests in civil society) excessively often make quite explicit and sometimes contradictory demands on them. Because these organizations are presumably illust rateatives of the public and are expect to behave in its interest, the press is expected to be especially vigilant on behalf of the public. Above all, public-sector organizations in democracies are subject to the influence of political parties.These parties have their own preference orderings of issues and their own sense of the public policies required to deal with them. Their agendas are essentially normative rarely do they brook qualification or interference on grounds of efficiency or similar considerations (Gortner et al. 1987 659). Members of governmental organizations, even when protected by civil service laws, dare political parties at considerable risk. This exposure may be extreme in the United States, but it is endemic to European and other parliamentary systems as well. AutonomyThis condition of multiple accountability, courtly and informal in nature (Cohen and Axelrod 1984), implies that political organizations are considerably less autonomous than private-sector org anizations. Not only are the formal chains of command multiple and complex, but informal influences and stuffs often limit, sometimes drastically, the degrees of freedom devote to persons in these organizations. Although managers in the private sector are as well as not free to act exactly as they force out prefer, their organizations (as long as they wage at bottom the law) are immensely more autonomous than public/political sector organizations are.Two additional characteristics relating to autonomy are worth noting. First, not only the goals of these organizations may not only be dictated from the outside, they may also be dependent on other external bodies to achieve them. Lawmakers need the executive branch, as do the courts, to have their policies enforced. Central governments need regional or local governments. A single policy may require the coordination and collaboration of different governmental bodies, many of which are in competition or conflict with each other.And , as I noted earlier, no-hit goal achievement may in part also lie in the hold of political parties and interest groups. Furthermore, governmental bodies or agencies often disagree about goals and policies. Evaluations of how well or poorly organizations are doing will be driven not by objective criteria (assuming they are getable) but rather by political ideology and partisanship. Even at bottom the comparable government, exist organizations will be in conflict over policies, such as in the case of ministries and departments that spend money while others have to worry about deficits, exchange rates, inflation, and so on.Even in exceedingly authoritarian or dictatorial political systems, such factors make organizations in the public/political sphere, if not radically different in kind from their counterparts in the private sector, then certainly different in the valence of the factors that I have been enumerating. To summarize, the missions of these public/political bodies, t heir membership, the resources provided for operations, the pay backs and punishments for good or bad goal achievement, and often the sheer survival of the organization itself are all matters that typically lie outside the organization itself.Hence, before taking initiatives, persons in political and governmental organizations will make careful internal and external assessments. First, they seek to discover how their superiors or flying colleagues may retrieve about a policy or mode of policy peachy punishment. Second, they look to how this policy or mode of implementation will sit with those internal or external forces that bum impinge on their maestro careers, their economic well-being, or the welfare of the organization itself.Third, they make assessments about what will lie in the way of their ambitions, including, perhaps, their propensity to make and enforce given policies. This basic pattern suggests that these organizations are under enormous pressure to engage in l earning. Attention will certainly be paid to other governmental agencies, political parties, labor unions, trade associations, religious or ethnic groups, the courts, the mass media, professional associations, the corporate community, and other political and governmental jurisdictions at home or a openhanded that may affect the organizations well-being.The list is very long of constituencies that wield enough force-out, formal or otherwise, to either dictate or oppose certain policies or facilitate or nullify their successful implementation (Dean 1981 133). Failures to perform calculations of this kind and to learn about these thingsand at a reasonably high level of competencewill hobble or defeat the persons or organizations involved. The corporate community has taken to engaging in somewhat similar scan in recent years, largely because of the internationalization of the firm.When managers extend their operations abroad, they come to appreciate the value, indeed the necessity, of scan these new environss for aspects that are not, strictly speaking, directly related to the market. As noted above this scanning has also been practiced at home, for national and local governments have come to exercise jurisdiction over matters that affect the life and situationly the profit or loss of private enterprise. atomic number 53 can generalize this drift by noting that managers are increasingly impelled to engage in scanning whenever gaps begin to appear between a corporations policies and its actual performance.Failure to catch sight of such gaps before the media do can carry severe consequences. Orientation to Action The conditions described above do not encourage much initiative by public/political-sector organizations. Action tends to be reactive, not proactive, and prophylactic, not sophisticated. Fresh ideas are typically viewed as threats to a delicate equilibrium between internal and external forces. Few people wish to risk taking steps that big businessman trigger chain reactions with unknown consequences.Conservatism, not risk-taking, becomes the modal orientation to action. Persons in the private sector, and the mass media, lament attitude, sometimes stridently. They overlook, perhaps, that they themselves are partly responsible for the shortcomings that they criticize. Conservatism also grows out of the fact that these organizations are much more tied to tradition and more deeply charge than is true in the private sector. These traits, too, make them extremely resistant to change.Whether legislatures (Cooper 1975), political parties (Panebianco 1988), or bureaucratic agencies (Powell and DiMaggio 1991 Scott 1995) are meant, the length of time they have been around will greatly condition what the organization is capable of doing, including its capacity to learn and, on this basis, to change. Max Webers (1958) reference to bureaucracys dead hand (p. 228) suggests that this type of conservatism is brought about by the very same char acteristics that he associated with legal-rational authority systems.Some writers have designate this phenomenon strong institutionalization (Panebianco 1988 53). Others have called it the embeddedness of values, or norms, that affect the cognitive systems of organizations (Herriott, Levinthal, and March 1985), the governmental sphere, therefore, endless examples show that efforts to better these organizations fail more often than not (Destler 1981 16770). This pattern does not mean that the bureaucrats who run these organizations are beyond anyones match or that change is impossible (Wood and Waterman 1994).It does mean, however, that organizational change is extraordinarily knotty to carry off, given the magnitude of inertial forces (Kaufman 1981). The budget process and goal displacement in the public/political sphere are additional factors that impinge on an orientation to action. For instance, not only are public budgets controlled from outside the organizations that depend on these allocations, in the short and medium terms, they can be modified and redirected only minimally, and at the margins. This circumstance is one reason why political scientists who wish to identify the most force-outful groups and organizations, within government tself and within civil society, will profile public budgetary allocations over fairly long periods of time. Goal displacement occurs when the personal interests and expediency of organizational leaders and members come to occult and replace the purpose(s) of the organization itself. This tendency is ubiquitous in the political sphere. Cooper (1975) nicely summed it up in his observation on the U. S. Congress He tack together that institution quite vulnerable to the deleterious effect the pursuit of residual goals of its members involves. These self-regarding goals distort policy orientations and block institutional illuminates by making individual self interest or collective partisan avail the focus of attention and the criterion of action (p. 337). Mayhew (1974) found that the best explanation for the action orientation of members of Congress is the strength of each members the desire be reelected. In extreme form, and in many different types of organizations, these characteristics actually result in a transformation of the organization itself (Perrow 1972 17887).The Environment Because the environment of organizations in the public/political sphere is so potently normative, the policies enacted there are not only temporary but also contested in their implementation every step of the way some(prenominal) inside and outside government. Knowing about these aspects of their environment, the managers of public/political organizations engage in a predictable type of environmental scanning and learning. For example, they learn whether to pay more attention to the legislature or to the executive office (Kaufman 1981).In order to be at least minimally effective in their environments, the organi zations involved must learn the ways and means of overcoming the kinds of constraints that I have been summarizing (Levin and Sanger 1994 668, 1716). Indeed, considerations of organizational efficiency may be and often are entirely irrelevant to decision-making and choice in the political sphere. Successful entrepreneurs in this context are the ones who learn how to conk and/or help their policies survive in an environmental landscape full of dangerous surprises and subject to frequent and radical change.The basic knowledge to be internalized is that this s fructifyter will remain continuous and that space for freedom of action will not last long. It is these qualitiesambiguity, messiness, and continuous contend and conflictin the political and governmental environment that lead political scientists to give considerable attention to power and its distribution two among and within organizations. That attention mud intense, but that power is an elusive concept invariably laden w ith all sorts of normative claims about to what type of power is legitimate and what type is not.In political science there is fairly broad agreement (Dahl 1968) that power is the ability, through whatsoever means, of one to person make another do his or her bidding, even and particularly in circumstances in which doing so is not what the other person wishes or prefers. Power and Organizations The Role and strain of Power Struggles Power, and the struggle over it, describe the essence of the political process. Rothman and Friedman (in this volume) note that scholars writing on organizational learning rarely take conflict and conflict resolution into consideration.They add that organizational conflict, even in the hands of authors as skilled as March and Olsen (1976), is not mentioned as one of the factors that may interdict the successful development of a learning cycle (see also March 1966). This neglect stems in part from the tendency, widespread in both the corporate community and management literature, to consider conflict itself as something extremely undesirable and potentially pathological and, therefore, as something to be defeated (Hardy and horse tick 1996 6278 Pfeffer 1981 29).It cannot be without negative consequences, either for the theory of organizational learning or for attempts to apply it in the workplace, that such organizations are almost never studied from the vantage point of power and of the competition that takes place to create and economize control of it or wrest it from others (Berthoin Antal 1998 Dierkes 1988 Hardy and Clegg 1996 631). One author (Kotter 1979 2) noted that the open want of power is widely considered a sign of bad management.Indeed, the authors of management literature not only hold over the behavior associated with power struggles but also condemn it as politicking, which is seen as parochial, selfish, divisive, and illegitimate (Hardy and Clegg 1996 629). Kotter (1979) found, for example, that in 2,000 arti cles published by the Harvard Business Review over a twenty-year period, only 5 of them included the word power in their titles. This finding is astounding. It suggests that power is treated like a dirty little family hole-and-corner(a) Everyone knows its there, but no one dares come right out to discuss it.One might imagine, though incorrectly, that the situation has changed for the better in recent decades. An examination of the Harvard Business Review with Kotters same question in mind shows that only 12 of more than 6,500 articles published in the period from 1975 to mid-1999 contained the word power in their titles and that 3 contained the word conflict. Leadership appeared in nine titles. In a prototype of abstracts of these articles, one finds, as expected, the term power somewhat more often than in the articles titles.But the term is almost never treated as a central concept that orients the way the researcher looks at an organization or develops propositions about its in ternal life. This finicky, keep-it-in-the-closet attitude toward power is puzzling. For political scientists, the question of power in organizations is central for many reasons because power is held unequally by its members, because there is a continuous struggle to change its distribution, because these inequalities and efforts to change them inevitably lead to internal tensions.A persistent quest in political science, therefore, is to neaten the structural aspects of public/political management that permits those involved to confront and handle power confrontations without defeating the purpose of the organization itself. Is There a Power Struggle? The puzzle of inattention to power in the fields of organizational theory and organizational learning is all the more intriguing given that leading organizational theorists, such as Argyris and Schon (1978, 1996) and Perrow (1972), have certainly addressed this matter.For example, Perrow treated organizational traits such as nepotism a nd particularism as means by which leaders of economic and noneconomic organizations maintain their power within them. Because these organizations are the tools of those who lead them and can be used to accumulate vast resources, a power struggle typically occurs over their control (pp. 1417). And because of goal displacement that may accompany such power struggles, organizations may well become things-in-themselves (pp. 1889).It is possible that leading theorists such as Argyris and Schon (1978, 1996) and Senge (1990) have themselves been excessively reticent in treating phenomena such as power struggles within the firm (Coopey 1995). It may be that corporate managers are in denial and therefore accurse to acknowledge that even they, like their counterparts in politics, are playing power games. Firms, and the literature about them, strive the beauty of teamwork and team players. Plants are organized around work teams and quality circles. Mission statements are always reiterated.H uman resource managers expend enormous energy instilling the firms culture as a distinctive way of doing things. People who excel at the approved traits are rewarded with promotions and stock options. All these practices might be cited as evidence that corporate behavior is instrumentally rational and that the search for power, especially for its own sake, is foreigner to the firm. This way of thinking and describing things leaves little room for attention to the power games that lie at the essence of most organizational life.Thus, making decisions about corporate strategic plans and the budgetary allocations that go with them defining of core crinklees and the sloughing of what is not core effecting mergers, acquisitions, and alliances and carrying out radical corporate restructuring that may separate thousands of persons from their jobs and yet dazzlingly reward others would typically be seen by political scientists as behavior that is quite similar to the kind of power strugg les that take place every day in public-sector organizations.Behind the veil of corporate myth and rhetoric, managers obviously know about this aspect of their environment as well. So do writers for the financial newspapers, where words such as power struggle appear much more frequently than they do in the management journals. How could it be otherwise when the efforts at leveraged buyouts, struggles to introduce one product line and abolish others, and differences over where and how best to invest abroad take on the monumental dimensions reported in the press?It would be astonishing if the persons involved in these events were found to actually believe that considerations of personal and organizational power are not germane(predicate) to them. Nevertheless, as Hardy and Clegg (1996) noted, the hidden ways in which senior managers use power stinker the scenes to further their position by shaping legitimacy, values technology and information are conveniently excluded from analysis. This nail down definition obscures the true workings of power and depoliticizes organizational life (p. 629). Attempts to correct the queasy orientation to the ingenuousness of conflict and power struggles have been relatively rare.One reason is that not alone the actors in the corporate community but also students of such things come to believe in the mythologies about empowered employees, concern for the stakeholders, the rationality of managerial decisions, and the pathology of power-seeking within organizations. Their belief is a pity in that, without doubt, the structure of power, explicit or implied rules about its use, and the norms that attach to overt and covert power-seeking will deeply affect the capacity of the organization to learn (Coopey 1995).In any case, there can be no doubting the fact, however much it may continue to be obscured in the corridors of corporate power, that struggles of this kind deeply affect corporate life its external behavior and who gets what , when, and how within these institutions (Coopey 1995 2025). The Benefits of Power Struggle Power struggle, of course, is not the only aspect of organizations worth study, and the world of politics is not incisively Hobbesian in nature. Cooperation is the obverse of conflict.How power is defined and whether the definition reflects left-wing or right-wing bias makes a difference in thinking about or conceptualizing the salience of power in organizations (Hardy and Clegg 1996 6235). In particular, it is essential that one avoid any definition or relatively broad conceptualization that does not take into account that, in any organization the existing rules of the game even if they are considered highly rational and legitimate, constitute in themselves the outcome of an earlier (and typically ongoing) struggle over control of an organizations resources (Hardy and Clegg 1996 629).When the ubiquitous existence of power struggle within organizations is acknowledged and put into proper pe rspective, when power-seeking (even when the impulse is entirely ego-centered and not driven by organizational needs) is accepted as normal behavior, and when it is recognized that no existing organizational structure is entirely neutral, only then can one hope to clarify what kind of single-loop or double-loop learning is likely to occur.For example, Coopey (1995) argued, correctly in my view, that where the distribution of power within an organization is hierarchical and asymmetrical, the type of organizational learning that proceeds in such contexts will tend to buttress the status quo. Their reasoning makes sense not just because, for example, the learning process tends to promote senior managers but also because the kind and quality of information to which those managers have regain becomes, in itself, an instrument for exercising and preserving ones favorable position in the power hierarchy.In the public sector, double-loop learning is even more impeded and therefore rarer t han in the private sphere. The reason is that politics, in both the organizational environment and political organizations, actually infuses every aspect of what public-sector organizations are and what they do. The more substantial the sphere of action or the issues treated by these bodies and the more public attention they draw, the more difficult it will be to reach consensus.And once consensus is reached, the more improbable it will be that anyone will either want to modify it or succeed in doing sono matter what the feedback about the policies and their efficacy may turn out to be (Smith and Deering 1984 26370). Double-loop learning in the public sphere is impeded also by the formal judicial separation of policy-making and policy implementation, as for example between legislative and administrative bodies. As noted earlier, policies are infrequently the choices of the organizations called on to implement them.In this setting, endemic to governmental systems, certain types of impediments to organizational learning tend to materialize. On the principals side, there may not be sufficient time, or technical competence, or interest to learn what is actually going on with policy implementation. The probability is low, therefore, that those who make policy and set organizational goals will ever get information that might encourage a realistic joint of goals and a rational specification of the means to be used in goal achievement.Organized interest groups are well aware of this gap. As a consequence, their typical strategy is to keep fighting for what they want, not only when alternative policies are up for consideration but also (sometimes particularly) after an unwanted policy has formally been adopted but must still face the vagaries of being carried out. On the agents side, whatever is learned about policy implementation that might urge a change of methods or of the policy itself may never be articulated at all, for to do so might upset an existing politic al equilibrium.Not only are these equilibria difficult to obtain in the first place, they often also involve an unspoken, symbiotic relationshipoften dubbed the Iron Triangle (e. g. Heclo 1978 102)between a specialized legislative committee, a bureaucratic agency responsible for administering the specialized policies, and the organized interests that benefit from particular policies, particular ways of implementing these policies, or both. Potential learning that would upset this balance of forces finds very rough sledding.The treatment of whistle-blowers, who sometimes go public with revelations of misguided or distorted policies or of bad methods used in their administration, is eloquent evidence of this problem. One way to overcome the stasis implied by these tendencies is to encourage power struggles, not to obscure them (Lindblom 1971 2142, 647). vigor will galvanize the attention of politicians and bureaucrats more than learning that organized groups with a vested interest in a given policy and large numbers of faithful voters are unhappy about a particular aspect of public policy.When these groups lie outside the Iron Triangle, they are far less inhibited by considerations of equilibria then when they are inside it. This single-issue focus is indeed one of the reasons why even slight and not well-financed public advocacy groups can sometimes be very effective in bringing about change (Heclo 1978). The trick is to maximize transparency, to encourage more group intervention as well as prompt the media to provide more, and more responsible, investigative reporting than they usually offer.Today it appears that the Internet is nimblely becoming an important instrument for the timely, accurate, and detailed exposure, now on a orbicular scale, of conditions that require correction. The organizational learning implications of this development are potentially enormous. Increased transparency implies, if nothing else, a more democratic, capillary diffusion an d sacramental manduction of information (see also Friedman, Lipshitz, and Overmeer in this volume).In an organizational context, whether in the private or the public sphere, this fact unsocial modifies the form, quality, and spread of learning it also brings about a modification of the organizational power structure itself. such(prenominal) modifications also mean that the structure and variety of conflict will change. In political science this kind of transformation, which widens and deepens competition, is considered to have healthy implications for the overall political system in which competition takes place.That is, benefits are expected to derive from the fact that the market becomes, in comparison to the more dirigiste state, more Smithian, less concentrated, and less dominated by a handful of competitors who, rhetoric aside, rarely pursue the general welfare but rather much narrower considerations. At the very least, increased transparency and the radiateing of the comp etitive sphere clearly require that political managers develop a set of skills that permit them to meet such challenges and function well within these constraints.New Signals from the Private Sector Something similar to this attitude about encouraging conflict may be developing in the private sector. Gortner et al. (1987) lamented that theories of the organization simply do not deal with the issue of politics, and . . . that these theories interpret power as an internal phenomenon usually related to the area of leadership (p. 76). But change may be afoot(predicate) in this respect for at least two reasons.Contributors to this volume as well as writers such as Pfeffer (1981, 1997), Coopey (1995) and Hardy and Clegg (1996) may well succeed in their efforts to raise self-consciousness and broaden and refine theories of the organization and organizational learning to include attention to power and politics. Second, variations and abrupt changes in the environment of business are ubiquit ous today and likely to intensify tomorrow. It could not be otherwise in an era of globalization of the firm, in which, more than ever before, firms venture into a wide variety of ethnic settings.In addition, managers increasingly come from a wide variety of cultures and professional backgrounds where values and norms are not needfully carbon copies of each other. An organizations capacity to read signals about politics and power distributions, outside as well as inside the firm, and to make quick, constructive adaptations to them will represent not just a luxury but also a necessary condition for establishing a competitive improvement in the global marketplace.In limiting cases, this capacity may actually become a necessary condition for survival. Power-driven behavior within the firm not only is endemic to such organizations but system spectacular irrespective of the degree to which the firm succeeds in creating an internal environment that is homogeneous, harmonious, and coll aborativean environment people by those who share corporate values and a corporate culture and who stress collective over individual goals (Handy 1993 12349).By definition, the firm is typically an organization that places high value on the competitive spirit. That spirit is an aspect of human behavior everywhere and that can scarcely be divorced from the impulse to obtain and hang on to disproportionate shares of power. Improved understanding of the structure of such internal competition also illuminates the relationship between these kinds of patterns and corporate learning (Coopey 1995 1978 Hardy and Clegg 1996 6335 Kotter 1979 939).Increased attention to power (even if the term itself is not used) is implicit in the corporate communitys recent encouragement of internal open expression of objections to existing policies and of open competition between units of the company and between its members. Bringing these universal underlying conditions to the surface may be inevitable, giv en how much more variegated todays large-scale companies are from those in the past, not just in technology, product lines, and personnel but above all in the great diversity of markets and cultures in which they now operate.The less homogeneous the international firm becomes, the more difficult it will be to mask the fact that corporate life, like political life, involves a good deal of organizational and individual struggle over power. Power Linkages and Networks Because conflict and power struggle in public-sector organizations are both internal and external, their managers are impelled to search the environment for opportunities to form alliances. sometimes such alliances are of the Iron Triangle variety, but they are certainly not limited to this form. The idea is to create structural linkages that will improve ones chances of governing.As public policies become more salient for the firm, the firm too, will experience increased need to expand its own networks beyond those that already exist in the marketplace. Linkages with public bodies, for example, cannot be optimized (as once may have been the case) through the use of consultants and lobbyists. Structures and capabilities consonant with the organization of direct networks come to replace or supplement these older approaches. Multinational corporations that operate abroad, where public policies represent new risks for the firm as well as new opportunities as well, have often travel in exactly this networking direction.One indicator of this change is the proliferation not just of equity joint ventures (as opposed to the once-dominant fetich of the wholly owned subsidiary) but also all manner of other interfirm alliance, designed to optimize, in abroad local markets, the use of firms and their managers who have extensive experience there. In the case of U. S. companies, this type of change was also spurred by the passage of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act a generation ago. At home, one immediate co nsequence of this legislation was a sharp increase in the number of in-house attorneys employed by American firms.Overseas, it led to a much more intense search for the ways and means of finding arrangements that can somehow enable overseas U. S. firms to engage in corporate behavior that was unexceptional abroad but suspect or even outright unacceptable at home. The globalization of enterprise, the growth of networks in which the firm becomes involved at home and abroad, also brings about a considerable extension of learning methods and horizons, if not a new type of organizational learning in the private sector. The international firm becomes more sensitized to power configurations and power equilibria.The search is broadened as well as intensified in order to identify aspects of the environment that might impinge on corporate success. The quality of intelligence relevant to business operations at home and abroad is improved, as is the knowledge about the location and means of acc ess to points in the decision-making process that relate to public policies affecting the foreign investor. A keen sense that each environment has its unique aspects as well as dimensions that are general to any environment impels the firm to sharpen its analytical instruments and thereby try to improve its learning.Efforts to create a total quality system come to include not just the production, distribution, and servicing of a firms products but also the firms ability to recognize power and power struggles for what they are and to attune its learning methods to profit from this new capability. Types of Power Distributions and Equilibria Although power equilibria are never permanent, they tend to last for a long time. The reform of governmental bodies tends to be greatly resisted because, even when reforms are relatively mild, they threaten existing equilibria (Seidman 1977).As a rule, unless quick and deep change is the goal, it is better for an organization (inside or outside the public/political sphere) to learn how to operate within an existing equilibrium than to make efforts to change it. Indeed, it is almost axiomatic that, where a radical departure in public policy is intended, creating a new organization is far preferable to seeking achievement of these new goals through the existing system (Levin and Sanger 1994 1723).Events of this kind, though rare, provide highly fluid opportunities to achieve first-mover advantages as new networks and a new equilibrium are established. In this regard, it makes a difference whether the overall configuration of the political system is monocratic or pluralist, unitary or federal, highly change or characterized by broad delegation or devolution of powers. That is, power equilibria at the microlevels will be influenced in no small measure by the configuration of the larger system in which these equilibria are embedded.Pluralism Pluralist systems tend to maximize not only the number of individuals and organizations able to intervene in the policy-making and policy implementation processes but also the number of channels through which the interventions occur. Pluralism implies minute and fragmented representation of interests. The underlying assumption is that equality of opportunity, central to democratic theory, should also apply to the policy-making process. It will obviously make a difference which groups prevail in these efforts to exercise influence.It is equally important whether and what kinds of groups can bring some order to the process by aggregating a number of small groups under a single organizational umbrella. Pluralism also invites much debate. In theory, when consensus is achieved, it is expected to be very strong, precisely because of widespread opportunities that interested parties have for being consulted and hearing the views of others. over again in theory, this system of broad company should also optimize the discovery both of best solutions and of innovative ideas abou t public policies and how best to achieve them.It is behind such policies, according to pluralist democratic theory, that one can expect the strongest collective effort to emerge. And given all of these assumptions, consensual policies are likely to be well administered and widely accepted as long as they achieve expected aims. Within this rich mosaic of interactive participation, organizational learning is presumably optimized, as are the efficacious making and implementation of public policies. There are also negative sides to pluralism, and they are well known to organizational theorists.A plethora of communication channels easily debaucheds into information overload. This overload in turn can lead to never-ending debates that whirl up in stalemates or paralysis. There may be too much talk, too many options raised, and little inclination, or indeed ability, to reach closure. An even more notable objection to this mode of decision-making is the raised probability that it will produce only lowest-common-denominator outcomes. The need to balance competing forces and to find acceptable compromises implies that only in extreme emergencies can pluralist systems adopt radical measures.Pluralism and the forceful, timely management of issues do not sit easily side by side. Hence, it seems valid to presume that such systems will not work well within a corporate structure that, almost by definition, is expected to be hierarchical and unitary (Hardy and Clegg 1996 6226). Monocratic and Unitary Systems Monocratic and unitary systems are highly concentrate. If they permit a broad representation of interests, it is likely to be within a framework that is much more disciplined than that of pluralist systems.Monocratic and unitary systems are able to act even when broad consensus may be wanting or impossible to bring about. Participation from the ground up, so to speak, is not so loose or permissive as to actually tie the hands of or paralyze those at the center. Comp ared to pluralist systems, monocratic arrangements tend to be less democratic (not to be confused with undemocratic). They may involve broad, well-articulated participation in policy-making and implementation, but within limits.They tend to be more illiberal of inputs that are judged to be dysfunctional. They are immensely more suspicious of interventions in the formal decision-making and policy implementation process by groups and organizations that are not official, or not officially approved by the government. The tensions between pluralistic/democratic and unitary/monocratic arrangements are not unlike those found within corporations that move in the direction of say-so of those located toward the bottom of the pyramidal hierarchy.As I have suggested, this pyramid is not just one of positions and authority but also of command and control. That is, as long as the pyramid remains a pyramid, even slightly, it is a power arrangement governed by rules that, with rare exceptions, are themselves the outcome of a power struggle. Serious efforts to empower persons who have not had very much power, or who through empowerment will come to exercise more of it than in the past, clearly imply a widening and intensify of participation in decision-making both in the making of corporate policies and in their implementation.It is no wonder that changes of this kind, as well as those designed to bring stakeholders meaningfully into such processes, are fraught with complications and that they usually degenerate into not much more than lip-service platitudes (Coopey 1995). Monocratic and unitary political systems, such as those typically found in Europe and elsewhere outside the United States (and to some extent outside Great Britain), accord very high status to the state writ large. Those who manage the state are more inclined to redirect, minimize, and, if necessary, tip over interference from civil society when this interference threatens to paralyze government.Reasons of state, as the justification is often called, will lead to closure of debate and then to public action, presumably in favor of the community as a whole. In monocratic systems, popular sovereignty and broad participation by the masses or by organized groups will not be permitted to place the state and its overriding welfare at risk. This attitude is similar to the posture of senior corporate managers who are scarcely about to tolerate modes of empowerment or participation that might cast serious doubt on the companys mission, the rationality of its basic long strategy, or the companys very survival.Nevertheless, in the corporate sphere, as in the sphere of the state, the powers available to managers must be and often are used to end an aura of legitimacy not just to existing rules and policies but also to the outcomes that derive from them (Hardy and Clegg 1996 630). Federalism Federalism adds another facet to this discussion. As a political concept that stands in opposition to that of unitary structures, federalism implies a division of power on the basis of territory.A much-touted advantage of federalism is that it permits the bringing together, under one central authority, of territorial units that differ quite markedly from each other in many ways. This would include, say, the size of their population or territory their racial or linguistic make up and a wide range of social, economic, and even political conditions. Federal systems represent ways of organizing and managing diversity. In the country of politics, experience has shown that these systems are therefore much more viable means of managing large nations than are highly centralized unitary systems.In fact, most of these nations are of the federal, not the unitary, varietyeven the Soviet Union and the Peoples Republic of China in their so-called totalitarian heyday. Federalism also maximizes the amount of experimentation (with different laws, institutions, electoral arrangements, administrative or ganizations, and the like) that can take place under a common political roof. This umbrella-like structure permits, indeed encourages, the search for best practice in institutional form and relationships and in policy-making and implementation. This lark of federalism encourages, permits, and, indeed encourages self-conscious learning.In the United States, for example, there are formal organizations designed to provide the individual states and major cities with information about the potentially innovative or effective approaches that each may be taking to, organizational procedures or public policy. Similar information-sharing institutions also exist at the international level. This institutionalized learning is designed in the broadest sense to raise the quality and lower the cost of governmental services. In a federal setting the political center shares a number of powers with other territorial units. Except in estricted areas, it cannot pretend to be the exclusive holder or ex erciser of power and authority. Even where in formal terms the political centers authority may be exclusive and where policies are expected to be uniformly administered throughout the systems territories and subunits, considerable local variation must be permitted. Unitary systems, by contrast, permit much less flexibility of this type. The central authority within such systems exercises nearly exclusive authority to make system-wide policies, and it is also expected that these policies will be uniformly administered everywhere.Any disagreement from centrally established policies, indeed any policy-making within subnational units, proceeds only with some sort of authorization by the center. As often said in France, if one wishes to know exactly what children might be doing at a certain hour of any school day, it is sufficient to consult the manual(a) issued by the appropriate ministry in Paris. The unitary form is highly analogous to the world-wide business firm, including firms o rganized by product group or division, in which authority and control are concentrated in a single, central organization.The preceding, post-war development of the multinational corporation, at least in the United States, proceeded for the most part on the basis of this model. It was thought that the revolutions in jet travel and electronics made such centralized control both desirable and feasible. That is, these changes in the speed and facility of travel and communication were said to make possible the global extension of the so-called Sloan model of the corporation, a model that had worked so well within the United States.Feedback and Learning No matter whether the basic structure is pluralistic or monocratic, federal or unitary, the need for feedback from which the center can presumably learn is universal. Federal systems, because they produce many streams of information, may be more open but less efficient than unitary systems. Unitary systems, although in theory narrower and easier to control than federal systems are in terms of information-producing channels, are at high risk of having information delayed, distorted, or misdirected.It is apparent, however, that the center often deludes itself into believing that, with a highly disciplined and centralized organizational weapon at its disposal (like the communist party under Stalin in the USSR or the Chinese Communist party under Mao), it can both learn and control what transpires at the periphery (Hough 1969). The fallacious assumption in this instance is that a centralized and highly disciplined organizational instrument, such as the Communist party, can prevail irrespective of whether the overall system is of the federal or unitary configuration.Pluralism and Federalism in the Firm? A pluralist and federal model of the command ill fits the generally held image of the firm and of other private-sector organizations. Decision-making of the kind represented by the typical firm can scarcely follow a plur alist model to the letter, at least not without a rethinking of a great many well-established notions of what a world-scale company should be and how it should be run. Within the firm great violence is placed on clear lines of authority, both horizontal and vertical.The global firm still tries to instill a single corporate culture so that the hierarchy of values, the operational norms, and the modus operandi will be essentially the same wherever its branches and units may be located. This model leaves little room for pluralist inputs and local diversity. Pluralist democracies and federal systems thrive (most of the time) on their multicultural dimensions. Rather than eliminate diversity, it is honored and encouraged. In the corporate world, much of what is claimed about decentralization, planning from the bottom up, and individual empowerment often is spurious.Senior managers in the corporate world are rarely able or inclined to practice the decentralization or the broad and deep p articipation that they may preach. much often than not they use the considerable powers at their disposal not to encourage debate that leads to bear but rather to mobilize consent itself (Hardy and Clegg 1996 626). In the public/political sector, a key test of how seriously the center wishes to encourage diversity and favor empowerment lies in the practice of devolution, as opposed to decentralization.Devolution, typically practiced on a territorial basis, substantially reduces the powers of the center over the periphery, sometimes drastically. The strongest indicator of this reduction is the empowerment of the periphery not only to make policies but also to tax income or otherwise raise capital in connection with these policies. Such transfers, in turn, encourage high levels of competition between the subnational units of federal systems, sometimes creating very difficult problems at the center.Devolution increases pluralism. When hierarchy is replaced by something compose of ra ther free-acting units, managers need to develop skills that are germane to these changed circumstances. It is one thing when a persons position makes it possible to mobilize consent and conforming behavior it is quite another story when both of these things must be generated within the context of a relatively open, participatory, and fluid system of reaching consensus on what should be done and how best to do it.It is possible that the globalization of enterprise will force an increase in genuinely federal arrangements on the firm, a shift that would certainly imply moving aside from a strict unitary, hierarchical model and award one that is genuinely more participatory, even if more difficult to manage. Charles Handy (1996) stated that such a change may be taking place (pp. 3356), although even he suggested that the application of federal principles to the corporate world will, perhaps inevitably, be sapless (pp. 10912).The creation of similar federal structures, even ones remai ning distant from devolution, requires a new look at many of the most canonical ideas about how best to organize and manage the profit-seeking enterprise. On close inspection, the sometimes spectacular downsizing and other changes in corporate structures since about 1990 do not appear to have brought about radical operational changes in hierarchical structure. In both the public and the private sectors, centralized control of organizations dies hard.Nevertheless, the federal thrust in many of todays global firms should not be underestimated. In the truly global firm, where multinationality is not just a label, traditional arrangements for strategic plans, corporate finance, and capital budgetingwhich are still basically monocratic and unitary in naturewill gradually be revised. It is conduct to think, as so many corporate managers still do, that the continuing electronic and information technology revolutions will permit efficient global control from a single, geographically dis

No comments:

Post a Comment